The main source of the rupee’s ascent nominally comes from sustained
foreign direct investment inflows (mainly to IRS Schemes) , portfolio
investment inflows due to the relatively high interest rates and the plunging
dollar. Since July 2007, the collapse of the sub-prime bubble has forced the US
to cut rates to save its collapsing banking system, which has sent the US
dollar plunging. The widening interest rate differential in favour of
the Mauritian rupee as interest rates on key currencies are brought down has
also been driving the Mauritian rupee to higher levels. The BOM has allowed the
exchange rate to appreciate to take pressure off imported inflation and also to
manage capital inflows. But increasing interest rates at a time when the world
as a whole is tending to a more benign interest rate regime attract the flow of
funds from abroad which contribute to worsening the problem the authorities
intend to solve. Up to December 2007, with both headline and core inflation on
the decline, the authorities felt quite confident they have at least been able to
anchor inflationary expectations and controlled the secondary effects of the
imported inflation . The monetary tightening, as reflected by the increase in
the Repo rate, has allowed a rather high interest rate differential to build up
and this has increased the flow of liquidity from abroad .The bigger the
interest rate differential, the bigger is the pressure of capital inflows . The
BOM was finding itself in a dilemma that their measures at hiking the interest
rates has further increased capital inflows that may turn out to be
inflationary. Broad monetary liabilities in 2007 were growing by 15.3 %, aggregate monetary
resources by 15.7% though total domestic credit were growing by only 9% ,of
which private sector credit at a moderate rate of 12% . There was thus an
urgent need to stem this flow of liquidity by calibrating its interest rate
measures appropriately. This explains the reduction in the Repo rate. This is a
difficult task at all times. Those
who erroneously claim that « il vaudrait mieux intervener sur la
quantité et non sur le prix » have not understood this simple
logic.
So what’s the
issue then ? The issue is that the Central bank is facing one of its toughest challenges as it finds itself
caught up between exporters lobby who
find themselves priced out of markets because
of the strong rupee and the exchange rate fundamentalists who believe that the way out of the inflation
problem is for the currency to appreciate
The proponents for a weaker rupee believe that the
present policy is mere short term stupidity bearing enormous long run
consequences. It will affect key areas of the economy such as Export Oriented
Enterprises / Manufacturing,/ tourism/ICT which are labour intensive and
destroy the employment growth being witnessed presently. This will hurt the poor
more than all this nonsense about controlling inflation. When the poor have no jobs
and no money – it is not a question of the
loss of purchasing power, but the loss
of his livelihood. They argue that the stronger exchange rate is already
taking a toll on exports. The growth forecasts of Export Oriented Enterprises (EOE) and tourism sectors
have been revised downwards and during the first semester of 2008, the tourism
sector has grown by only 5% whereas in the last quarter of 2007 , 13 EPZ
enterprises closed down and EOE exports grew by only 2.8%. EOE exports growth
have been declining over successive quarters from 23% to 17%, to 10% to 2.8% in
the last quarter..
It is true that an appreciation in the rupee can
slow down our exports and one argument for a weaker rupee is that that Mauritius needs
to promote exports. This argument overlooks the fact that export
competitiveness is not determined by the nominal exchange rate, but by the real
exchange rate, which also takes into account the differences in the rates of
inflation of other countries. If our trading partners or competitors have low
inflation, their costs of production remain low. We lose export competitiveness
when our inflation rate is higher than theirs. So what we are gaining by
keeping the rupee from getting stronger, we may be losing through inflation.
But they counter attack that prices are climbing in response to global factors and that monetary
or exchange rate measures cannot, by itself, bring down imported inflation in
the economy. Some of their experts have worked out the simple inflation
reducing effects of exchange rate appreciation casting some doubts on the exchange
rate fundamentalists, perhaps too simplistic, notions of exchange rate
pass-through.
“The most successful country — the US . With an
exchange rate depreciation of 25 per cent, it achieved a 7 percentage point
lower inflation rate. China
is the third worst country — excess inflation of 11.4 per cent. The country
with the most monetarist concern about inflation, Germany (via the Bundesbank before
and now the ECB), has the worst inflation fighting record among developed
economies (excepting Sweden ).
Given the large 27 per cent appreciation in the euro, inflation in Germany should
have been -6.5 per cent instead of 2.8 per cent! The comparison between the US and Germany is
stark and as follows. Germany
has a currency appreciation of 27 per cent and an inflation rate acceleration
from 1.8 to 2.8 per cent. The US
has a 25 per cent depreciation and an inflation rate acceleration of only 0.4
percentage points.” Courtesy
Surjit Bhalla..
Country
|
CPI Inflation
(%)
|
|
Change in Inflation (% points)
|
Currency Change
|
Predicted Inflation
|
Excess
Infaltion
|
|
2006
|
2008
|
2008/06
|
2008/06(%)
|
2008(%)
|
2008(%)
|
|
2.8
|
7.2
|
4.5
|
-38.9
|
-8.9
|
16.1
|
|
0.7
|
4.1
|
3.4
|
-38.4
|
-10.8
|
14.9
|
|
0.9
|
8.3
|
7.4
|
-13.3
|
-3.1
|
11.4
|
|
0.6
|
3.1
|
2.5
|
-27.3
|
-7.6
|
10.7
|
|
1.2
|
6.3
|
5.1
|
-16
|
-3.6
|
9.9
|
|
3.1
|
3.5
|
0.5
|
-29.8
|
-5.9
|
9.4
|
|
4
|
7.8
|
3.8
|
-18.4
|
-1.5
|
9.3
|
|
1.8
|
2.8
|
1
|
-27.6
|
-6.5
|
9.2
|
|
1.4
|
2.4
|
1
|
-27
|
-6.7
|
9.1
|
|
2.1
|
2.9
|
0.8
|
-27.6
|
-6.2
|
9.1
|
|
3.9
|
4.3
|
0.4
|
-27.6
|
-4.3
|
8.7
|
|
2.8
|
3
|
0.2
|
-26.4
|
-5.2
|
8.1
|
|
5.4
|
4.5
|
-0.9
|
-24.8
|
-2.1
|
6.6
|
|
10.5
|
12
|
1.4
|
-16.8
|
5.5
|
6.5
|
|
5.4
|
5.3
|
-0.2
|
-21.7
|
-1.1
|
6.3
|
|
-0.1
|
0.7
|
0.8
|
-17.5
|
-5.3
|
6
|
|
1
|
3.8
|
2.8
|
-8.3
|
-1.5
|
5.3
|
|
2
|
2.5
|
0.5
|
-14.8
|
-2.5
|
4.9
|
|
1.2
|
6.1
|
4.9
|
0.3
|
1.3
|
4.8
|
|
4.6
|
5.4
|
0.8
|
-10.6
|
1.4
|
3.9
|
|
3.6
|
3.6
|
0
|
-2.8
|
2.8
|
0.8
|
|
3.8
|
9.3
|
5.5
|
23.8
|
11
|
-1.6
|
|
3.5
|
3.9
|
0.4
|
25
|
11
|
-7.1
|
In Mauritius , the appreciating rupee
has not succeeded in denting inflationary pressures, they claim. The 8.7 % rate
of inflation for FY07/08 is explained by the prevalence of administered prices,
the increased use of subsidies and the delay in adjustment to imported
inflation and the changes in the new HBS basket for calculating CPI. We have thus been subjected to some
very doubtful and questionable claims about the instantaneous benefits of rupee
appreciation . The scourge of high inflation has not been vanquished by the
appreciating rupee. These very economists who in the not too distant past were
arguing that we have little policy leeway against imported inflation have now
become the apostle of the "strong
rupee is good for inflation" crowd. La rupee forte « a permis de maintenir le prix de
l’essence pendant trois mois consecutifs malgre la hausse vertigineux du brut ».
Such arguments ne fait pas honneur to the economist class,. While
other economies are responding and adjusting to the international price signals
(that’s what the APM was meant for), we are subsidising petrol and gas, and
users of cars and middle class users of LPG, at a price that is nowhere
reflecting the global prices and at the cost of creating big gaps in the trade
account; is that sustainable.?
One should also be careful about copycat references
to Singapore
which deliberately allowed its exchange rate to appreciate in the mid 1980s .
From a low manufacturing base, Singapore
reinvented itself and went into high-end manufacturing and financial services.
We willingly missed the boat for massive human capital formation in the late
1980s and opted instead for the prodigal “no tax budgets” , while Singapore coming out of its successful
job creation programme in the late 70s prepared the economy to move to its next
phase of development. Prior to the appreciation of the rupee, much before the
economy, de maniere deliberee,
the Government started a program of economic restructuring. This was
achieved by modifying education policies, expanding technology and computer
education, offering financial incentives to industrial enterprises and
launching a productivity campaign
Some glimpses of the preparedness of Singapore and
the strategies that contributed to facilitate its transition to an increasingly
private sector-led knowledge-based economy. I hope, these will help to discard those
simplistic comparisons for a more meaningful investigation into the key
ingredients of their success --particularly human resource development,
efficient resource allocation, and openness to modern technology. These are: a) Singapore
productivity growth was indeed very low until the 1980s but improved
significantly to level comparable to OECDs in the 1990s; b) their Human
resource Development strategy was to improve the training of Singaporean
workers through government training institutes. A typical training program
would meet twice a week for three-hour sessions over a two year period. The
training was voluntary and free and it was geared to the needs of the companies
operating in Singapore
at that time. But the newly trained, highly motivated Singaporean workers not
only replicated the old production process but began to make improvements that
further lowered costs and enabled the economy to absorb the appreciating
exchange rate. There developed in Singapore a culture of innovation.
The government training program proved to be so beneficial to employers that
they acquiesced to a special tax to help pay for it. c) Singapore branched out
into the creation of a Science Park to share research between government and
industry a national computer board to encourage the computerization of Singapore’s
schools, offices and homes a tripling of
the size of the two engineering universities the creation of a $50 million
venture capital fund to encourage Singaporean start-up companies but which
would also fund start-ups outside of Singapore. And d) established in October
1979, the Skills Development Fund provides financial incentives to encourage
employers to continuously upgrade their skills of their workers through
structured training. And So on
Most of our East Asian economies
have current account surpluses, while Mauritius has a huge current account deficit of above 5
per cent of GDP in 2007 and 8 % in 206/07.
So, based on fundamentals, while it is understood that these economies
should let their currencies appreciate, why should the Mauritian rupee, given
the fundamentals, not depreciate? What
if the Mauritian Rupee is over--valued as a result of
the “ dutch disease”. Can we say that we
have a strong high –value manufacturing base, with growing trade in all
segments and excellent export growth that are powering this strong rupee ?
The sustained
capital flows to the IRS and real estate sector have been the main cause of the
appreciation of the rupee. These flows
do not enhance our productivity and flexibility. They are temporary and they do
not in any way boost our export potential. There is no transfer of technology
or know-how or any multiplier effects on the economy. . We can only stem the rupee appreciation by imposing
limits on these types of unproductive capital inflows and reprioritise our
development projects and reconsider our development strategy. Given the limited absorptive capacity of the
economy, greater priority should be given to those programmes and projects that
rapidly enhance our productivity and boost our export potential.
Only then can we
afford to leave it to the market to determine the exchange rate and the BOM can
then focus on a single objective — low and stable inflation. Whatever monetary
measures we take for inflation control, they will be mainly aimed at preventing
expectations to become entrenched and the spills over into second-round effects
if supplies are constrained.